>body bgcolor="#FFFFFF" marginwidth="100" leftmargin="100">
Home | Humour | Essays | Travel | Images |
The Social Ideology of
the Motorcar
by André Gorz
please read this first
The worst thing about cars
is that they are like castles or villas by the sea: luxury goods invented for
the exclusive pleasure of a very rich minority, and which in conception and
nature were never intended for the people. Unlike the vacuum cleaner, the radio,
or the bicycle, which retain their use value when everyone has one, the car,
like a villa by the sea, is only desirable and useful insofar as the masses
don't have one. That is how in both conception and original purpose the car
is a luxury good. And the essence of luxury is that it cannot be democratised.
If everyone can have luxury, no one gets any advantages from it. On the contrary,
everyone diddles, cheats, and frustrates everyone else, and is diddled, cheated,
and frustrated in return.
This is pretty much common knowledge in the case of the seaside villas. No politico
has yet dared to claim that to democratise the right to vacation would mean
a villa with private beach for every family. Everyone understands that if each
of 13 or 14 million families were to use only 10 meters of the coast, it would
take 140,000km of beach in order for all of them to have their share! To give
everyone his or her share would be to cut up the beaches in such little strips-or
to squeeze the villas so tightly together-that their use value would be nil
and their advantage over a hotel complex would disappear. In short, democratisation
of access to the beaches point to only one solution-the collectivist one. And
this solution is necessarily at war with the luxury of the private beach, which
is a privilege that a small minority takes as their right at the expense of
all.
Now, why is it that what is perfectly obvious in the case of the beaches is
not generally acknowledged to be the case for transportation? Like the beach
house, doesn't a car occupy scarce space? Doesn't it deprive the others who
use the roads (pedestrians, cyclists, streetcar and bus drivers)? Doesn't it
lose its use value when everyone uses his or her own? And yet there are plenty
of politicians who insist that every family has the right to at least one car
and that it's up to the "government" to make it possible for everyone to park
conveniently, drive easily in the city, and go on holiday at the same time as
everyone else, going 70 mph on the roads to vacation spots.
The monstrousness of this demagogic nonsense is immediately apparent, and yet
even the left doesn't disdain resorting to it. Why is the car treated like a
sacred cow? Why, unlike other "privative" goods, isn't it recognised as an antisocial
luxury? The answer should be sought in the following two aspects of driving:
1.Mass motoring effects an absolute triumph of bourgeois ideology on the level
of daily life. It gives and supports in everyone the illusion that each individual
can seek his or her own benefit at the expense of everyone else. Take the cruel
and aggressive selfishness of the driver who at any moment is figuratively killing
the "others," who appear merely as physical obstacles to his or her own speed.
This aggressive and competitive selfishness marks the arrival of universally
bourgeois behaviour, and has come into being since driving has become commonplace.
("You'll never have socialism with that kind of people," an East German friend
told me, upset by the spectacle of Paris traffic).
2.The automobile is the
paradoxical example of a luxury object that has been devalued by its own spread.
But this practical devaluation has not yet been followed by an ideological devaluation.
The myth of the pleasure and benefit of the car persists, though if mass transportation
were widespread its superiority would be striking. The persistence of this myth
is easily explained. The spread of the private car has displaced mass transportation
and altered city planning and housing in such a way that it transfers to the
car functions which its own spread has made necessary. An ideological ("cultural")
revolution would be needed to break this circle. Obviously this is not to be
expected from the ruling class (either right or left).
Let us look more closely now at these two points.
When the car was invented, it was to provide a few of the very rich with a completely
unprecedented privilege: that of travelling much faster than everyone else.
No one up to then had ever dreamt of it. The speed of all coaches was essentially
the same, whether you were rich or poor. The carriages of the rich didn't go
any faster than the carts of the peasants, and trains carried everyone at the
same speed (they didn't begin to have different speeds until they began to compete
with the automobile and the aeroplane). Thus, until the turn of the century,
the elite did not travel at a different speed from the people. The motorcar
was going to change all that. For the first time class differences were to be
extended to speed and to the means of transportation.
This means of transportation at first seemed unattainable to the masses -- it
was so different from ordinary means. There was no comparison between the motorcar
and the others: the cart, the train, the bicycle, or the horse-car. Exceptional
beings went out in self-propelled vehicles that weighed at least a ton and whose
extremely complicated mechanical organs were as mysterious as they were hidden
from view. For one important aspect of the automobile myth is that for the first
time people were riding in private vehicles whose operating mechanisms were
completely unknown to them and whose maintenance and feeding they had to entrust
to specialists. Here is the paradox of the automobile: it appears to confer
on its owners limitless freedom, allowing them to travel when and where they
choose at a speed equal to or greater than that of the train. But actually,
this seeming independence has for its underside a radical dependency. Unlike
the horse rider, the wagon driver, or the cyclist, the motorist was going to
depend for the fuel supply, as well as for the smallest kind of repair, on dealers
and specialists in engines, lubrication, and ignition, and on the interchangeability
of parts. Unlike all previous owners of a means of locomotion, the motorist's
relationship to his or her vehicle was to be that of user and consumer-and not
owner and master. This vehicle, in other words, would oblige the owner to consume
and use a host of commercial services and industrial products that could only
be provided by some third party. The apparent independence of the automobile
owner was only concealing the actual radical dependency.
The oil magnates were the first to perceive the prize that could be extracted
from the wide distribution of the motorcar. If people could be induced to travel
in cars, they could be sold the fuel necessary to move them. For the first time
in history, people would become dependent for their locomotion on a commercial
source of energy. There would be as many customers for the oil industry as there
were motorists-and since there would be as many motorists as there were families,
the entire population would become the oil merchants' customers. The dream of
every capitalist was about to come true. Everyone was going to depend for their
daily needs on a commodity that a single industry held as a monopoly.
All that was left was to get the population to drive cars. Little persuasion
would be needed. It would be enough to get the price of a car down by using
mass production and the assembly line. People would fall all over themselves
to buy it. They fell over themselves all right, without noticing they were being
led by the nose. What, in fact, did the automobile industry offer them? Just
this: "From now on, like the nobility and the bourgeoisie, you too will have
the privilege of driving faster than everybody else. In a motorcar society the
privilege of the elite is made available to you."
People rushed to buy cars until, as the working class began to buy them as well,
defrauded motorists realised they had been had. They had been promised a bourgeois
privilege, they had gone into debt to acquire it, and now they saw that everyone
else could also get one. What good is a privilege if everyone can have it? It's
a fool's game. Worse, it pits everyone against everyone else. General paralysis
is brought on by a general clash. For when everyone claims the right to drive
at the privileged speed of the bourgeoisie, everything comes to a halt, and
the speed of city traffic plummets-in Boston as in Paris, Rome, or London-to
below that of the horsecar; at rush hours the average speed on the open road
falls below the speed of a bicyclist.
Nothing helps. All the solutions have been tried. They all end up making things
worse. No matter if they increase the number of city expressways, beltways,
elevated crossways, 16- lane highways, and toll roads, the result is always
the same. The more roads there are in service, the more cars clog them, and
city traffic becomes more paralysingly congested. As long as there are cities,
the problem will remain unsolved. No matter how wide and fast a superhighway
is, the speed at which vehicles can come off it to enter the city cannot be
greater than the average speed on the city streets. As long as the average speed
in Paris is 10 to 20 kmh, depending on the time of day, no one will be able
to get off the beltways and autoroutes around and into the capital at more than
10 to 20 kmh.
The same is true for all cities. It is impossible to drive at more than an average
of 20 kmh in the tangled network of streets, avenues, and boulevards that characterise
the traditional cities. The introduction of faster vehicles inevitably disrupts
city traffic, causing bottlenecks-and finally complete paralysis.
If the car is to prevail, there's still one solution: get rid of the cities.
That is, string them out for hundreds of miles along enormous roads, making
them into highway suburbs. That's what's been done in the United States. Ivan
Illich sums up the effect in these startling figures: "The typical American
devotes more than 1500 hours a year (which is 30 hours a week, or 4 hours a
day, including Sundays) to his [or her] car. This includes the time spent behind
the wheel, both in motion and stopped, the hours of work to pay for it and to
pay for gas, tires, tolls, insurance, tickets, and taxes. Thus it takes this
American 1500 hours to go 6000 miles (in the course of a year). Three and a
half miles take him (or her) one hour. In countries that do not have a transportation
industry, people travel at exactly this speed on foot, with the added advantage
that they can go wherever they want and aren't restricted to asphalt roads."
It is true, Illich points out, that in non-industrialised countries travel uses
only 3 to 8% of people's free time (which comes to about two to six hours a
week). Thus a person on foot covers as many miles in an hour devoted to travel
as a person in a car, but devotes 5 to 10 times less time in travel. Moral:
The more widespread fast vehicles are within a society, the more time -- beyond
a certain point -- people will spend and lose on travel. It's a mathematical
fact.
The reason? We've just seen it: The cities and towns have been broken up into
endless highway suburbs, for that was the only way to avoid traffic congestion
in residential centres. But the underside of this solution is obvious: ultimately
people can't get around conveniently because they are far away from everything.
To make room for the cars, distances have increased. People live far from their
work, far from school, far from the supermarket - which then requires a second
car so the shopping can be done and the children driven to school. Outings?
Out of the question. Friends? There are the neighbours... and that's it. In
the final analysis, the car wastes more time than it saves and creates more
distance than it overcomes. Of course, you can get yourself to work doing 60
mph, but that's because you live 30 miles from your job and are willing to give
half an hour to the last 6 miles. To sum it all up: "A good part of each day's
work goes to pay for the travel necessary to get to work." (Ivan Illich).
Maybe you are saying, "But at least in this way you can escape the hell of the
city once the workday is over." There we are, now we know: "the city," the great
city which for generations was considered a marvel, the only place worth living,
is now considered to be a "hell." Everyone wants to escape from it, to live
in the country. Why this reversal? For only one reason. The car has made the
big city uninhabitable. It has made it stinking, noisy, suffocating, dusty,
so congested that nobody wants to go out in the evening anymore. Thus, since
cars have killed the city, we need faster cars to escape on superhighways to
suburbs that are even farther away. What an impeccable circular argument: give
us more cars so that we can escape the destruction caused by cars.
From being a luxury item and a sign of privilege, the car has thus become a
vital necessity. You have to have one so as to escape from
the urban hell of the cars. Capitalist industry has thus won the game: the superfluous
has become necessary. There's no longer any need to persuade people that they
want a car; it's necessity is a fact of life. It is true that one may have one's
doubts when watching the motorised escape along the exodus roads. Between 8
and 9:30 a.m., between 5:30 and 7 p.m., and on weekends for five and six hours
the escape routes stretch out into bumper-to-bumper processions going (at best)
the speed of a bicyclist and in a dense cloud of gasoline fumes. What remains
of the car's advantages? What is left when, inevitably, the top speed on the
roads is limited to exactly the speed of the slowest car?
Fair enough. After killing the city, the car is killing the car. Having promised
everyone they would be able to go faster, the automobile industry ends up with
the unrelentingly predictable result that everyone has to go as slowly as the
very slowest, at a speed determined by the simple laws of fluid dynamics. Worse:
having been invented to allow its owner to go where he or she wishes, at the
time and speed he or she wishes, the car becomes, of all vehicles, the most
slavish, risky, undependable and uncomfortable. Even if you leave yourself an
extravagant amount of time, you never know when the bottlenecks will let you
get there. You are bound to the road as inexorably as the train to its rails.
No more than the railway traveller can you stop on impulse, and like the train
you must go at a speed decided by someone else. Summing up, the car has none
of the advantages of the train and all of its disadvantages, plus some of its
own: vibration, cramped space, the danger of accidents, the effort necessary
to drive it.
And yet, you may say, people don't take the train. Of course! How could they?
Have you ever tried to go from Boston to New York by train? Or from Ivry to
Treport? Or from Garches to Fountainebleau? Or Colombes to l'Isle-Adam? Have
you tried on a summer Saturday or Sunday? Well, then, try it and good luck to
you! You'll observe that automobile capitalism has thought of everything. Just
when the car is killing the car, it arranges for the alternatives to disappear,
thus making the car compulsory. So first the capitalist state allowed the rail
connections between the cities and the surrounding countryside to fall to pieces,
and then it did away with them. The only ones that have been spared are the
high-speed intercity connections that compete with the airlines for a bourgeois
clientele. There's progress for you!
The truth is, no one really has any choice. You aren't free to have a car or
not because the suburban world is designed to be a function of the car-and,
more and more, so is the city world. That is why the ideal revolutionary solution,
which is to do away with the car in favour of the bicycle, the streetcar, the
bus, and the driverless taxi, is not even applicable any longer in the big commuter
cities like Los Angeles, Detroit, Houston, Trappes, or even Brussels, which
are built by and for the automobile. These splintered cities are strung out
along empty streets lined with identical developments; and their urban landscape
(a desert) says, "These streets are made for driving as quickly as possible
from work to home and vice versa. You go through here, you don't live here.
At the end of the workday everyone ought to stay at home, and anyone found on
the street after nightfall should be considered suspect of plotting evil." In
some American cities the act of strolling in the streets at night is grounds
for suspicion of a crime.
So, the jig is up? No, but the alternative to the car will have to be comprehensive.
For in order for people to be able to give up their cars, it won't be enough
to offer them more comfortable mass transportation. They will have to be able
to do without transportation altogether because they'll feel at home in their
neighbourhoods, their community. their human-sized cities, and they will take
pleasure in walking from work to home-on foot, or if need be by bicycle. No
means of fast transportation and escape will ever compensate for the vexation
of living in an uninhabitable city in which no one feels at home or the irritation
of only going into the city to work or, on the other hand, to be alone and sleep.
"People," writes Illich, "will break the chains of overpowering transportation
when they come once again to love as their own territory their own particular
beat, and to dread getting too far away from it." But in order to love "one's
territory" it must first of all be made liveable, and not trafficable. The neighbourhood
or community must once again become a microcosm shaped by and for all human
activities, where people can work, live, relax, learn, communicate, and knock
about, and which they manage together as the place of their life in common.
When someone asked him how people would spend their time after the revolution,
when capitalist wastefulness had been done away with, Marcuse answered, "We
will tear down the big cities and build new ones. That will keep us busy for
a while."
These new cities might be federations of communities (or neighbourhoods) surrounded
by green belts whose citizens-and especially the schoolchildren-will spend several
hours a week growing the fresh produce they need. To get around everyday they
would be able to use all kinds of transportation adapted to a medium-sized town:
municipal bicycles, trolleys or trolley-buses, electric taxis without drivers.
For longer trips into the country, as well as for guests, a pool of communal
automobiles would be available in neighbourhood garages. The car would no longer
be a necessity. Everything will have changed: the world, life, people. And this
will not have come about all by itself.
Meanwhile, what is to be done to get there? Above all, never make transportation
an issue by itself. Always connect it to the problem of the city, of the social
division of labour, and to the way this compartmentalises the many dimensions
of life. One place for work, another for "living," a third for shopping, a fourth
for learning, a fifth for entertainment. The way our space is arranged carries
on the disintegration of people that begins with the division of labour in the
factory. It cuts a person into slices, it cuts our time, our life, into separate
slices so that in each one you are a passive consumer at the mercy of the merchants,
so that it never occurs to you that work, culture, communication, pleasure,
satisfaction of needs, and personal life can and should be one and the same
thing: a unified life, sustained by the social fabric of the community.
Le Sauvage, September-October
1973
TOP OF PAGE